Please see PDF version







CONVEXITY BIAS IN THE PRICING
OF EURODOLLAR SWAPS

VLADIMIR POZI3NYAKOV AND J. MICHAEL STEELE

ABSTRACT. The traditional use of LIBOR futures prices to obtain surrogates for the Eurodollar forward rates is proved to yield a systematic bias in the pricing of Eurodollar swaps when one assumes that the yield curve is well described by the HeathJarrowMorton model. The resulting theoretical inequality is consistent with the empirical observations of Burghardt and Hoskins (1995), and it provide a theoretical basis for price anomalies that are suggested by more recent empirical data.

1. INTRODUCTION

The prices of Eurodollar swaps are uniquely determined by the value of the Eurodollar forward rates, and the main problem in pricing a Eurodollar swap comes from the unfortunate fact that the Eurodollar forward rates are not directly observable. This has led to the uneasy custom among market practitioners to use LIBOR futures prices in order to calculate surrogates for the missing forward rates. It has long been understood that the daily settlement of futures contracts implies that these surrogates are imperfect, yet much remains to be discovered about the true nature of the biases that may be introduced when these surrogates are used to price Eurodollar swaps.
The main goal here is to show that under a reasonably general model for the term structure of interest rates, one can prove that there is a systematic bias in the customary process for pricing interest rate swaps. Our result provides a theoretical confirmation of the empirical observations of Burghardt and Hoskins (1995), and it also provides a basis for the rnore precise analysis of swap prices.
The principal results are developed in Section 4, but, before those results can be derived, we need to introduce some notation and to recall some familiar properties of the HeathJarrowMorton term structure model. We then develop a technical result that implies the WM framework typically generates a term structure model where futures rates are systematically higher than the corresponding forward rates. Section 4 then uses this technical result to obtain results on the biases that are produced from using futures rates as surrogates for forward rates in the pricing of zerocoupon bonds and swaps.
Finally, Section 5 provides a brief analysis of the recent empirical behavior of swap rates and their relationship to the a priori bounds obtained here. The data suggest several engaging anomalies, and, in particular, one finds that there is at

1991 Mathematics Subject Classification. Primary: 911328; Secondary: 60H05, 60G44.
Key words and phrases. HeathJarrowMorton model, WM model, interest rates, LIBOR, futures prices, arbitrage pricing, swap, equivalent martingale measures.

1


2 VLADIMIR POMNYAKOV AND J. MICHAEL STEELE

least modest evidence that the arbitrage opportunities suggested by Burghardt and Hoskins may still survive.

2. BACKGROUND ON THE WM MODEL

Our analysis is based on a term structure model of Heath, Jarrow, and Morton (1992) that has become one of the standard tools for the theoretical analysis of fixed income securities and their associated derivatives. This model is well discussed in several recent books, such as Ba,xter and Rennie (1996), Duffie (1996), and Musiela and Rutkowski (1997)), but some review of the WM model seems useful here in order to set notation and to keel) our derivation of the pricing inequality reasonably selfcontained.
If P(t, T) denotes the price at time t of a bond that pays one dollar at the maturity date T < r, then the first step in the construction of an HJM model is the assumption that P(t, T) has an integral representation,

(1) P (t, T) = exp f (t, u) du 0 < t < T < r,

where the processes {f (t, T) : 0 < t < T < r} model the instantaneous forward rate that should reflect the interest rate available at time t for a riskless loan that begins at date T and which is paid back "an instant" later. Moreover, under the WM model, one further assumes that f (t, T) may be written as a stochastic integral

t t
(2) f (t, T) = f (0, T) + 10 a(u, T) du + 10 a(u, T)LdBu,

where Bt denotes an ndimensional Brownian motion and the two processes

{ce(u, T) : 0 < u < T:5 r} and {u(u,T) : 0 < u < T < r}

are respectively R and R' valued and adapted to the standard filtration J1:t of {Bt}. Also, one should note that the symbol L in the second integral of (2) denotes the vector transpose, and both of the processes Bt and o, (u, T) are viewed as column vectors.
The representation (1) imposes almost no real constraint on P(t, T) except nonnegativity and the normalization P(T, T) = 1. In fact, the essential nature of the WM model only becomes evident once one restricts attention to a subclass of instantaneous forward rates f (t, T) for which one can guarantee that there are no arbitrage opportunities between bonds of differing maturities.

THE FORWARD RATE DRIFT RESTRICTION

An essential feature of the WM model is that in almost any economically meaningful context, the coefficient processes a (t, T) and o, (t, T) of the SDE for f (t, T) must satisfy a certain simple analytical relationship. Specifically, one knows that a(t, T) may be assumed to be of the form

T a (t, T) = a (t, T) ' [y (t) + 1, a (t, u) du]


CONVEXITY BIAS AND EURODOLLAR SWAPS 3

where y(t) is an adapted ndimensional process such that
(4) E exp y(u)LdBu   ' 1' Iy(,)12 d.)
( lo*r 2 ',

When this identity holds, we say that f (t, T) satisfies the forward rate drift restriction, and we call the process y(t) that appears in this formula the market price for risk. The economic motivation from this condition comes from the fact that it implies several useful properties of the probability measure P defined on JF, by

(5) fl(A) = E 1A CXP y(u)LdB~   ' Iy(u)12 d.)
1 ( IT 2
Specifically, if we set
t
(6) r (t) f (t, t) and 0(t) = exp( 10 r(u) du),

then for each T the discounted process {P(t, T)10(t) : 0 < t < T} is a Pmartingale with respect to the filtration.Ft. The process r(t) = f (t, t) is called the spot rate r(t) and fl(t) is called the accumulation factor (or discount factor), and 13(t) is simply the value of a deposit that begins with a balance of one dollar at time zero and that accrues interest according to the stochastic spot rate r(u) during the period 0 < U < t. 
The measure P is commonly called the equivalent martingale measure since P has the same null sets as P and since the process {P(t,T)10(t) : 0 < t < T} is a Pmartingale for each T E [0, r]. The importance of P comes from the classic results of Harrison and Kreps (1979) and Harrison and Pliska (1981) that tell us that existence of such a measure is enough to guarantee that there are no arbitrage opportunities between the bonds of differing maturities.

A BASIC REPRESENTATION

By Girsanov's theorem and the definition (5) of P, one sees that vector process
defined by
t
(7) bt = Bt + 10 7(u) du

is a standard PBrownian motion, and Heath, Jarrow, and Morton (1992) observed that the SDE for {f (t, T)} leads one to a particularly useful SDE for {P(t, T)} Specifically, {P(t, T)} satisfies the bt SDE

(8) dP(t, T) = P(t, T)[ r(t) dt + a(t, T)Ldht
where a(t, T) is the ndimensional column vector of integrated volatilities defined by
T
(9) a (t, T) a (t, u) du.
t
The SDE (8) and the definition of 0(t) then permit one to show that for any initial
yield curve P(O, T) one has
(10) P(t, T) = P(O, T)O(t) exp [10 t a(s, T)'dh,  2 J' la(,, T) 12 d,]


4 VLADIMIR POMNYAKOV AND J. MICHAEL STEELE

A price process {P(t, T)} that satisfies equations (1) through (10) is called an HJM yield curve model. Here we will find that the integral representation (10) gives one easy access to some basic qualitative features of the price process {P(t, T)}.

3. THE FUTURES RATES  FORWARD RATES INEQUALITY

Next, we need to recall some of the conventions and introduce some notation for LIBOR rates, specifically the "ALIBOR rate" that is offered at time t for a Eurodollar deposit for a maturity of A360 days. This rate is also called the spot ALIBOR rate when one needs to emphasize its distinction from the corresponding forward or futures rates and it is denoted by LA (t).
By convention LIBOR rates are quote as addon yields, and our first task here is to work out the relation between ALIBOR rates and the prices of the implied zerocoupon bonds. If LA(t) denotes the ALIBOR rate at time t, then, in terms of a corresponding zero coupon bond, the arithmetic of addon yields one finds the representation,

(11) LA (t) 1 0 < t <
P(t,t+,\)
and, in the same way, if LA (t, T) denotes the forward A LIBOR rate for the future time period [T, T + Al one has the representation
(12) LA (t, T) = 1 G P(t, T)  1 0 < t < T < r.
A P(t, T + A)
The rate LA (t, T) reflects the (addon) interest rate available at time t for a riskless loan that begins at date T and which is paid back at time T + X The instantaneous forward rate f (t, T) can be written in terms of the forward ALIBOR rate as f (t, T) = limA jo LA (t, T).
Now, if ~ denotes the expectation with respect to the equivalent martingale measure P, then the conditional expectation under E can be used to provide a formula for the ALIBOR futures rate FA(t, T). Specifically, we have the representation
(13) F, (t, T) = i~ 1 X, ( 757(TT1  ' ) J.)c~ ] = EZ [LA (T) 1 JF, ] 0 < t < T < 7..

From the perspective of pure theory, one can take the formula (13) simply as the definition of the futures rate. Nevertheless, this formula is also widely considered to provide a sensible representation of real world futures prices, and there is a long history of modelling futures prices by such martingales. In particular, Karatzas and Shreve (1998, p. 43) provide a useful discussion of the economic motivation behind this definition.

MAIN RESULT: THE FUTURES RATEFoRWARD RATE INEQUALITY

Our main result is an inequality which asserts that the typical WM framework yields a term structure that forces the ALIBOR futures rates FA(t, T) to be higher than the associated forward ALIBOR rates LA(tJ) with probability one. This bound is analogous to Theorem 1 of Pozdnyalcov and Steele (2002), but here one meets two differences. First, we now deal with a more general volatility structure. Second, our analysis makes better used of the fact that the forward ALIBOR rate process LA(., T) is a submartingale under the equivalent martingale measure.


CONVEXITY BIAS AND EURODOLLAR SWAPS 5

Theorem 1 (Futures RateForward Rate Inequality). For all 0 < t < T < 7, the futures rate F,\ (t, T) and the forward rate L,\ (t, T) satisfy the inequality

(14) F,\ (t, T) ~: L,\ (t, T)
with probability one, provided that the underlying HM family of bond prices
{P(t, T) : 0 < t < T < r} satisfies the constant sign condition which asserts that for any t and i = 1, 2, .., n the volatility coefficient ai (t, .) has the same sign.

Proof. To begin, we will show that for any t, U, and T such that 0 < t < U < T < r we have a simple threeterm product representation of the ratio P(t, T)IP(t, U) any two bond prices :

(15) P(t, T) P(O, T) (t, T, U)~(ty T, U),
7~(t,u) ~~ P (0, U)"
where the second factor 77(t, T, U) is given by
t t
77(t, T, U) = exp [a(s, T)  a(s, U)] ' dh~  la(s, T)  a(s, U) 12 ds
[1, 2 10
and the third factor ~(t, T, U) is given by

~(t, T, U) = exp a(s, U)' [a(s, T)  a(s, U)] ds

To cheek this representation we just note that the basic bond formula (10) gives us
t t
P(t, T) P(OJ),3fflexp fo'a(s,T)'dB,lfo'la(s,T)I'ds
2
t t
P(t, U) P(O, U)O(t) exp fo'a(s, U)LdB,  1 fo' la(s, U) 12 ds
2

P (0, T) X
P(O, U)
x exp [a(s, T)  a(s, U)IL db,,  [la(,, T) 12 la(,, U) 12 1 ds
[10 2 10
P(O, T) 77(t, T, U)~(t, T, U). P(O, U) The main benefit of this representation comes from the analytic properties of the last two factors.
The essential property of the third factor is that the process Ws, T, U)} is monotone decreasing as a function of s. To check this fact, we first note that by definition, the integrated volatility vector a(t, T) has components
T
ai(t, T) ci (t, u) du,
t
so the constant sign condition for the values of a(t, u), t < u < U tells us that for each s E [0, U] and all i = 1, 2,..., n, we have with probability one that ai (s, T) :5 ai (s, U) :5 0 or 0 < ai (s, U) :5 ai (s, T). As a consequence, one finds that

a(s, U)' [a(s, T)  a(s, U)] < 0, a.s., so by the integral representation of ~(s, T, U) one finds that it must be a decreasing function of s.


6 VLADIMIR POWNYAKOV AND J. MICHAEL STEELE

The essential property of the second factor {i7(., T, U)} is that it is a positive local Pmartingale, and, thus, by Fatou's lemma {77(., T, U)} must also be a positive Asupermartingale. Next, for any 0 < U < T < 7 one then finds that the bond price ratio P(., T)IP(., U) is the product of a positive Psupermartingale 17(., T, U), a decreasing positive process ~(., T, U), and a nonnegative constant, so P(, T)IP(., U) must itself be a positive Asupermartingale.
Now, by Jensen's inequality, the convexity of x ~4 11x on (0, oo), and the supermartingale property of the bond price ratio P(., T)IP(., U) for any choice of 0 < t < s < U < T < r, we have

1 P (t, U)
P(s, T) E[P(s, T)IP(s, U)JJrt] ~~ 75(t, T)Mt, U) P (t, T)
i~ ( E(~ 1 ill ) > 1

The bottom line is that the reciprocal P(., U)I^., T) is a flsubmartingale.
Since the forward ALIBOR rate LA (t, T) is a nonnegative affine function of the ratio process P(., T) IP(., T + \), we see that {LA (., T)} is also a submartingale under the equivalent martingale measure P. Finally, the ALIBOR futures rate FA(., T) is a Pmartingale for which one has

FA (T, T) = LA (T) = LA (T, T),
so the submartingale property of the forward ALIBOR rate and the martingale property of ALIBOR futures rate together imply that

L,x(t,T):5E[L,x(T,T)I,'7t]=E[L,x(T)I'7t]=F,x(t,T) a.s.,
just as we intended to show. F1

One should note that there are several methods that lead to a proof that the bond ratio Mt = P(t, T)IP(t, U) is a Asubmartingale. The most immediate benefit of the present method may simply be that it is direct and selfcontained, but there may also be benefits to be found in our introduction of the three term factorization (15). Certainly, the factorization provides more information than just the knowledge that Mt = P(t, T)IP(t, U) is a Asubmartingale, although so far no specific use has been found for this additional information. Nevertheless, over time, one may expect that the factorization (15) will find a further role.

THE SIGN CONDITION

The only nonstandard condition that one needs in order to obtain the futures ratesforward rates inequality is the constant sign condition, and one should note that this condition is met by most  but not all  of the specific W11 models that have been used in practice. For example, all of the examples in Heath, Jarrow, and Morton (1992) satisfy the constant sign condition, and in most cases the condition is trivial to cheek. In the continuous HoLee model one has o(w, t, T) = o where o > 0 is constant, and in the Vasicek model one has u(w, t, T) = a exp(6(T  t)) > 0; moreover, the twofactor combinations of these models considered by Musiela and Rutkowski (1998, p. 324) satisfy the constant sign condition. One can also cheek that most of the models considered by Amin and Morton (1994) satisfy the constant sign condition, but some do not; for example, their "Linear AbsolutJ model with or (w, t, T) = oo + ul (T  t) will not satisfy the constant sign condition for if oo and ul have opposite signs and T is sufficiently large.


CONVEXITY BIAS AND EURODOLLAR SWAPS 7

4. THE SWAP INEQUALITY

The most immediately useful consequence of the futures rateforward rate inequality is that it quickly leads one to a theoretical upper bound for the swap rate. Moreover, this bound has the interesting and potentially important feature that it holds uniformly over a large class of the I1J11 models.
Before proving the swap rate inequality, we need to introduce some notation and recall some standard definitions. If TO ~~ 0 and r. are given and we set

T1 = To + A, T2 = To + 2A, ..., TN = To + NA,
then the forward start payer swap settled in arrears (or, in short, the swap) is a series of payments A [LA (Tk)  re] that are made at the successive times Tk+l with k = 0,..., N  1. In this payment formula, the constant r, is called the preassigned fixed rate of interest, and N is called the length of the swap. The time TO is called the start date, and, for the forward start payer swap settled in arrears, the times TO, ..., TN 1 are called the reset dates and the times TI, ..., TN are called the settlement dates.
The time TO arbitrage price 7r(K) of the cash flows of a swap is given by
N 1
7r (K) '3(TO ) A (LA (Tk FT~
k=0 O(Tk+I)
and one can easily cheek that 7r(K) has the representation

7r(r,) = 1  AK[P(To, T1) ++ P(To, TN)]  P(To, TN),
a formula that is also derived and discussed in Musiela and Rutkowski (1997, p. 388). Finally, the swap rate ro is such value of the preassigned fixed rate of interest r, that the time TO arbitrage price of the cash flows associated with the swap contract is zero, i.e.

(16) K0 1  P(TI, TN)
A(P(TO, T1) + ''' + P(TO, TNW
Now we are ready to present the main result of this section. This proof requires little more than seeing how the definition of the swap rate fits together with the futures rate inequality, but the resulting inequality still serves nicely when one tries to sort out the theoretical basis of the empirical observations of Burghardt and Hoskins (1995).
Theorem 2 (Swap Rate Inequality). Suppose {P(t, T) : 0 < t < T < r} denotes an HJM family of bond prices for which the constant sign condition of Theorem 1 holds. The swap rate ro then satisfies the following swap rate inequality:
1 + AL,(T,,)  fl' 1 (1 + AFA (To, Tk))
(17) Ko :5 + (1 + \FA (TO, T1)) k=l
+ + HN 1 (1 + AF,\ (TO, Tk))
k=l
Proof. First we need to develop a lower bound for the price of zerocoupon bond P(To, Tk) with k = 1, 2,..., N. Using the telescopic product and the formulas for the forward and spot LIBOR we have that

P(TO, Tk) P(TO, T1)P(TO, T2) P (TO, Tk)
P (TO, T1 P(TO, Tk1)

(18) 1 1
1 + ALA (To) 1 + A LA (To, T1 ) 1 + ALA (To, Tk  1)


8 VLADIMIR POWNYAKOV AND J. MICHAEL STEELE

Now, if we replace the forward XLIBOR rates in this identity by the corresponding ALIBOR futures rates, then Theorem 1 tells us that the identity becomes an inequality,

(19) P(TO, Tk) >
+ \L, CV,,) 1 + \F, (T,,, T, 1 + \F, (T,,, T,
Finally, to obtain the swap rate inequality (17), we just need to substitute all
the bond prices P(To,TN) in the formula for the swap rate (16) by their lower
bounds from the bond inequality (19). When we the divide both the numerator
and denominator of the resulting estimate by (1 + AL.\ (To)) ', we see that the proof
of the Swap Rate Inequality (17) is complete. E]

Surely the most interesting features of the Swap Rate Inequality is the fact that the expression on the righthand side of Q7) has often been used as an approximation to the true value of the swap rate ro. For example, the use of this approximation is expressly recommended in l~nding and CapitalMarkets Activities Manual, InterestRate Swaps.' Nevertheless, Theorem 2 suggests us that this widely used procedure may be subject to systematic biases. Specifically, in a world where the yield curve is well modelled by an HJM model that satisfies the constant volatility condition, we see from the Swap Rate Inequality (17) that the suggested approximation is almost surely an overestimate of the true swap rate. In a completely parallel way, the bond inequality (19) also shows that one faces an almost sure downward bias when one uses the expression on the righthand side of (19) as an approximation for the price of zerocoupon bond. Nevertheless, as in Burghardt and Hoskins (1995) note (p. 63), such bond price approximations are also widely used.

5. EmPIRICAL OBSERVATIONS

One does not know a priori if the swap rate inequality (17) reflects a law of economic reality or if it is an artifact of the HJM model. One naturally wants to know if swap rate inequality (17) is evident in realworld swap rates. Fortunately, since July 3, 2000 the Federal Reserve Board has included the U.S. dollar par swap rates in the H.15 Daily Update, 2 so an empirical analysis of the swap rate inequality (17) can at least be begun.
In Figure 1, we provide a box plot of the value of the traditional swap rate approximation minus the observed swap rate (as derived from the FRB H.15 Daily Update). For example, in the first column of Figure 1, the top of the box marks the third quartile Q3, the bottom marks the first quartile Q,, the line interior to the box marks the median, and the value of the "upper fence" U = Q3 + 1.5(Q3  Q1) and 9ower fence" L = Q1  1.5M Q,) are indicated by the square brackets. Observed differences beyond these fences are plotted individually as horizontal bars. Thus, if the Iyear swap rate on July 3, 2000 is 7.10% and the corresponding theoretical bound is ~7.146%, then the plotted difference is .046%. Column one of Figure 1 summarizes the observed differences for the lyear swap rates for each of the 247 trading days in the study period, and the remaining columns summarize the observed differences for the swap rates with maturities of 2,3,4,5 and 7 years.

'This document is publicly available on the website of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System www.bog.frb.fed.us/boarddocs/SupManual/ (see, e.g. p.7)
2see www. federalreserve. gov/releases/1115


CONVEXITY BIAS AND EURODOLLAR SWAPS 9

77

C~ 

. ..........

C?

lyear 2year 3year 4year 5year 7year

FIGURE 1. Box plots of the observed difference between the theoretical upper bounds and the observed swap rates for all trading days of the period July 2000  June 2001

OBSERVATIONS ON MATURITIES OF 1 To 7 YEARS

The data summarized by Figure 1 suggest several plausible inferences.
• For swaps rate with a relatively long timeto maturity (4,5 and 7 years), one finds that the gap between the theoretical upper bound and the observed swap rate is byandlarge positive, just as theory would suggest.
• One also sees that the longer timetomaturity the wider observed gap, and again this finding is consistent with our deductions under the HJM model.
• In contrast, one finds that for swaps with short maturities there are many days when the observed difference is negative, and this is at variance with the swap rate inequality (17) which predicts all of the observed differences should be positive. Ominously, the swaps with maturity of one year have a negative empirical gap almost 75% of the time.
Clearly the oneyear swap rates deserve closer scrutiny, and in Figure 2 we provide for oneyear swaps a monthbymonth box plot for the gap between the theoretical upper bound on the swap rates and the observed swap rates.

OBSERVATIONS OVER ALL MATURITIES
The picture one draws from the data summarized in Figure 2 is much less compatible with the theoretical consequences of the WM model. 111 particular, one finds:
The violation of the theoretical upper bound are common for oneyear swaps. In fact, for six of the months in the study period one finds that more
than 75% of the observed differences were negative, while theory would pre~ dict that there would be no negative differences.


10 VLADIMIR POWNYAKOV AND J. MICHAEL STEELE

7 7 ...... .... ..

Jul Aug Sap Oct Nov Dec Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun

FIGURE 2. Box plots of the observed difference between the theoretical upper bounds and the observed lyear swap rates month by month for the period July 2000  June 2001

• The month of November 2000 was particularly extreme, and virtually all the observed differences are negative.
• The predominant gap size less than 5 basis points, but for the negative gaps one finds gap sizes that are a bit smaller. The violations of the theoretical bounds were typically less than 3 basis points.
One is hard pressed to say if gaps of the size observed here are economically significant, although the discussion of Burghardt and Hoskins (1995, p. 69) suggests that they may be. The more conservative conclusion that one might draw is that a constant sign volatility WM model for futures rates may not be appropriate when the end goal is the pricing swap rates with short maturities. Even here one needs to be alert to possibility that the observed deficiencies may be remedied by more detailed models which take into account features such as transaction costs, counter party risk, or the fact that realworld futures are not continuously marked to market.

DATA RESOURCES AND COMPUTATIONAL DETAILS

The Swap Rate Inequality (17) has three inputs: the swap rate ro, the spot LIBOR quote L.\ (To), and the LIBOR futures rates F.\ (TO, Tk). Here TO denotes the current time and N is the length of the swap. so, for the lyear swap linked to the 3month LIBOR, one has A = .25 and N = 4.
The only quantities in the Swap Rate Inequality that are not directly observed are the futures rates. Specifically, the Chicago Mercantile Exchange quotes the Eurodollar futures prices, not the futures rates, so one must make the obvious


CONVEXITY BIAS AND EURODOLLAR SWAPS 11

conversion (futures rate =1futures price/100), but, unfortunately, there are two further problems with the CME data. The first is that one needs futures rates with the maturities that are not directly quoted, and the second is the more subtle problem that the rate quotes are not pegged to precisely the same times.
The swap rates published in the FRB H.15 Daily Update are based on information 3 obtained from acknowledged market makers as of 11:00 a.m. local time in New York, and one would surely like to have futures price quotes as of the same time as the swap rate survey. Unfortunately, the publicly available 4 data on Chicago Mercantile Exchange Eurodollar futures prices only cover the daily open, closing, highest and lowest futures prices. Rather than choosing to ignore the possible difference between Chicago opening prices and NYC 11:00 a.m. prices, we decided to report the observed gaps based on the highest futures rates. This choice was motivated by the desire to provide the most conservative estimate of the upper bound; since the righthand side of the Swap Rate Inequality is an increasing function of the futures rates f.\ (TO, Tk), our use of the reported CME highest futures rate leads to a value that we can be sure to be an honest upper bound.
There were no further computational decisions of substance, but perhaps some small points should be recorded. We followed the tradition of using cubic splines to interpolate the term structure (as, for example, in Grinblatt and Jegadeesh (1996)), and we also used cubic splines to interpolate the term structure of the futures rates. For each day one has about 40 futures prices with maturities up to 10 years that can be used in order to construct an interpolated term structure of futures rates, so the interpolated rates should be rather reliable. The cubic spline interpolation was performed with the standard SPlus function spline. The swap rate quotes provided in H. 15 are stated on semiannual basis so the upper bounds were converted to annual rates by the usual transformation x ~4 (1 + x/2)2  1 after they were computed.

6. CONCLUDING REMARKS

The Futures Rate  Forward Rate Inequality (14) and the Swap Rate Inequality (17) were proved here under the assumption that the stochastic behavior of the yield curve can be specified by an WM Model that satisfies the constant sign condition. Nevertheless, the phenomenon suggested by these inequalities is not necessarily restricted to such a model. The inequalities (14) and (17) can probably be stressed passed the breaking point if the constant sign condition is brutally violated, but we conjecture that for any economically feasible WM model one will find that both inequalities will hold. Naturally, one difficult element of this conjecture is the embedded project of explaining just which of the HJM models are indeed economically realistic.
In fact, a richer question is whether there might be useful analogs to the Futures Rate  Forward Rate Inequality (14) or the Swap Rate Inequality (17) that hold in much greater generality, perhaps even for yield curve models that are outside of the WM class of models. If the Futures Rate  Forward Rate Inequality (14) and the and the Swap Rate Inequality (17) do indeed reflect bona fide market realities,

3see press release of ISDA http://www.isda.org/press/a603981.html
4These can be obtained from www.barchart.com/cme/cmedta.htm, as and other locations, and LIBOR quotes are most easily obtained from the British Bankers' Association www.bba.org.uk.


12 VLADIMIR POZDNYAKOV AND J. MICHAEL STEELE

then one may well Conjecture that there are analogs for these inequalities for a very wide range of yield curve models.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: We are pleased to thank a referee for a suggestion that allowed us to remove an unnecessary regularity condition from Theorem 1 and to thank Krishna Ramaswamy for discussions on the intraday noncontemporaneous pricing of swaps and futures between New York and Chicago.

REFERENCES

[1] Amin, K. and Morton, A., Implied Volatility Functions in ArbitrageFree Term Structure Models, Journal of Financial Economics 35 (1994) 141180.
[21 Baxter, M. and Rennie, A., Financial Calculus: An Introduction to Derivative Pricing, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1996.
[31 Burghardt, G. and Hoskins, B., A question of bias, Risk 8 (1995) 6370.
[4] Duffle, D., Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory, 2nd ed., Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 1996.
[5] Grinblatt, M. and Jegadeesh, N., Relative Pricing of Eurodollar Futures and Forward Contracts, Journal of Finance, 51 (1996) 14991522.
[6] Harrison, J.M. and Kreps, D.M. Martingales and Arbitrage in Multiperiod Security Markets, Journal ofEconomic Theory, 20 (1979) 381408.
[7] Harrison, J.M. and Pliska, S., Martingales and Stochastic Integrals in the Theory of Continuous Trading, Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 11 (1981) 215260.
[8] Heath, D., Jarrow, R., and Morton, A., Bond pricing and the term structure of interest rates. A new methodology for contingent claim valuation, Econometrica 60 (1992) 77105.
[91 Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S.E., Methods of Mathematical Finance, Springer, New York, 1998.
[10) Musiela, M. and Rutkowski, M., Martingale Methods in Financial Modelling, Springer, New
York, 1997.
[111 Pozdnyakov, V. and Steele, J.M., A Bound on LIBOR Futures Prices for HJM Yield Curve Models, Technical report 0204, Department of Statistics, University of Connecticut, 2002.

DEPARTMENT OF STATISTICS, UNIVERSITY OF CONNECTICUT, 215 GLENBROOK RD, STORRS CT 062694120

DEPARTMENT OF STATISTICS, WHARTON SCHOOL, UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA, STEINBERG HALLDIETRICH HALL 3000, UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA, PHILADELPHIA PA 19104
Email address: bobagstat.uconn.edu steele@wharton.upenn.edu